Agnieszka Poczta-Wajda, PhD

The Poznań University of Economics

Department of Macroeconomics and Agricultural Economics

 

 

 

COMPETITIVENESS OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS FROM WELL-DEVELOPED COUNTRIES ON WORLD MARKETS IN THE LIGHT OF DIFFERENT LIBERALIZATION SCENARIOS

 

 

Introduction

Competitiveness is a process in which producers try to present an offer better than the others in order to encourage a buyer to chose their product [Iwan 2006]. A product is said to be competitive when it is better that the alternative one in regard to a specific criterion, i.e. price, quality or another feature. Agricultural products are considered to be an example of very homogenous goods, so price is very often a criterion which decides about their competitiveness. Agricultural products from developing countries are usually cheaper than those produced in developed countries mainly because developing countries enjoy some comparative advantages like better natural conditions and cheaper labour. Market share measures a competitive position of a good [Kasprzyk 2006]. Agricultural products from developing countries should therefore be more price competitive than the similar products from developed countries and possess significant share in world agricultural export. But this is not the case.

         In the beginning of 60’s, share of developed countries in world agricultural import accounted for 60% and in world agricultural export for 50%. By the middle of 80’s, these values changed a lot and a share of developed countries in world agricultural import declined to 40% and share in world agricultural export raised to 70%. What is more, this process is still progressing [Tyers 1992, WTO Database]. It is happening because of the very protective agricultural policy of developed countries (especially EU, US and Japan). Measures of market access, export subsidies and domestic financial support cause that producers from developing countries find it difficult to sell their products on the markets of developed countries, whereas producers from developed countries are able to sell their products on the world markets at a very cheap prices. Consequences of this situation are especially adverse for the least developed countries, in which trade with agricultural product (non-processed) has a crucial meaning for their economy and employment. Financial support for the farmers from developed countries influences the prices on world markets and reduce them under the level of profitability in many developing countries [Koo, Kennedy 2006]. This problem has been recognized on the international arena and the World Trade Organization (WTO) leads constant negotiations which aim to liberalize international trade with agricultural products. This process seems to be extremely difficult because of the protests of farmers’ lobbies from developed countries. On the one hand, farmers are afraid of competition exacerbation on domestic markets, and on the other hand, they do not want to lose their own competitiveness on the world markets [Kosewska, Kalicki 2008]. 

         The aim of this paper is to indicate how chosen measures of trade policy (tariffs and export subsidies) from developed countries influence prices on internal and external agricultural markets and the same determine competitive position of producer. Further, author of this paper is going to analyze the effects of future potential liberalization of agricultural trade under the WTO on the competitiveness of agricultural products from developed countries. The partial equilibrium model of agricultural sector AGLINK will be used to evaluate different liberalization scenarios.

 

Impact of intervention trade policy of developed countries on the competitiveness of agricultural products

         A country which share of world trade flows is big enough that it can influence world markets and the equilibrium price is called to be a “big” one from the economic point of view [Świerkocki 2004]. Well-developed countries, because of their share in world agricultural trade, are “big” countries and that is why the measures of intervention used in well-developed countries influence also prices on the world markets. Figure 1 illustrates economics consequences of export subsidy in a country A, which is a “big” country, and its impact on the world market price.    

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Figure 1. Economic consequences of a „big” country interference in export price level

Source: R. Tyers, K. Anderson, Disarray in World Food Markets. A Quantitative Assessment. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge 1992, p. 129.

 

In the base situation, price on world market amounts Pw. Country A decides to support export, introduces export subsidy and the same rises domestic price from Pw to P. Amount of export increases from CQ (=0X) to C’Q’ (=0X’). At the same time, additional amount of export from country A on the world market lowers the world prices to the level Pw. Country A must extend the value of subsidy to Pw’P. Of course the winners are producers from country A, who can sell more at higher price (area abdc), however consumers from this country lose (area aefc). Difference between producers’ advantages and consumers’ disadvantages represents area ebdf (or area gach). One must also remember to consider taxpayer lose (area gaij). Total  net effect for the country A welfare is negative. A part of this lost will be compensated on the world market by the gains of foreign importers (area jhci), however the world net welfare will also decline (area ghj). The conclusion is that a “big” country, which rises the price of good over the world level, loses more than a “small” country in the similar situation and the lost of world net welfare is also bigger [Koo, Kennedy 2006].

Figure 2 illustrates economics consequences of tariff in a country A, which is a “big” country, and its impact on the world market price.    

 


           

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Figure 2. Economic consequences of a „big” country interference in import price level

Source: R. Tyers, K. Anderson, Disarray in World Food Markets. A Quantitative Assessment. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge 1992, p. 131.

 

Country A decides to protect domestic producers from the foreign competition and introduces a tariff. Domestic price increases from world level Pw to level P. Amount of production in country A rises from 0Q to 0Q’ and amount of consumption falls from QC (=0M) to Q’C’ (=0M’). Lower import demand in country A causes decline of world price to level Pw’. In order to keep domestic price at level P, country A must introduce a higher tariff Pw’P. Area abcd (or eghf) represents the value of tariffs coming into country A budget. Producers’ gains are equal to area gaji, whereas consumers’ loses are illustrated by area igbk. Net welfare effect will depend from the relation between area jabk and area abcd. This relation will in turn depend from the elasticity of demand for the import from country A (the lower elasticity, the bigger lost) and the elasticity of supply of the rest of the world (the higher elasticity, the bigger lost). However it is worth mentioning, that the effect for the world net welfare will be negative (area efl) and the effect for the rest of the world net welfare will also be adverse (area hfli).

         Presented examples of economic consequences of tariff and export subsidy introduction in a “big” country show how well-developed countries influence competitive situation on the world markets. They do not only support domestic producers and let them gain higher prices, but also decrease prices on world markets which reduce the profitability of production in the other countries. Decline of prices on the world markets is not harmful for producers from well-developed countries, because it is being compensated with subsidies or higher domestic prices. One can find this situation on many agricultural markets. Liberalization of trade with agricultural goods under the WTO (reduction of tariffs and withdrawal of export subsidies) should therefore result in increase of prices on the world agricultural markets and decline in well-developed countries share in agricultural export. Price competitiveness of products from well-developed countries should decline towards products from developing countries, which use comparative advantages (cheaper means of production).         

 

Scenarios of agricultural trade liberalization on the chosen agricultural market with the use of AGLINK model

         Agricultural trade liberalization, as presented above, could lead to lost of price competitiveness of supported agricultural products from well-developed countries. Because results of Doha Round are still very dubious, agricultural economists try to predict effects of different scenarios of WTO negotiations on agriculture. Global economic models of equilibrium might be very useful in such analysis. With the use of these models one can survey quantitative relations between the whole economies, as well as single sectors and economies [van Togeren, van Meijl, Surry 2001]. Usually we distinguish two types of global economic models: general equilibrium models (cover the whole economies) and partial equilibrium models (cover only one sector).

         In this survey, a partial equilibrium model AGLINK-Cosimo was used. Module AGLINK is a dynamic, recursive, demand-supply partial equilibrium model of agricultural sector in OECD member countries and aggregate of the rest of the world. It was presented for the first time in 1992 by the OECD and was used for mid-term prognosis of changes in agricultural market variables in 10 member countries/groups caused by the shifts in agricultural policy. It was then completed with four non-member[1] countries, which had an important meaning in world trade with agricultural goods and in 2004 it was combined with FAO Cosimo module, which included other non-OECD countries. Because AGLINK is a partial equilibrium model it embraces only chosen agricultural markets[2]. It is assumed that other sectors do not influence the agricultural sector, unless they are included in demand or supply equations as exogenous variables (i.e. macroeconomic data) [Thompson, Smith, Elasri 2007]. Variables in model include annual values of supply, consumption, stocks, trade flows, prices[3] and measures of trade policy (tariffs, tariff rate quotas, export subsidies) and domestic support policy, which vary in every country[4]. Version 2006 of the model includes 10 800 equations and more than 30 000 variables from 39 countries and 16 regions. 

         One of the applications of the model is the possibility to produce mid-term forecasts of market variables changes as a result of different scenarios of agricultural and trade policy reforms. OECD, each year, publishes a base simulation in which it is assumed that agricultural policies in countries included in the model and macroeconomic conditions will not change. Analysis of any eventual changes in agricultural policy should be done with reference to the OECD base simulation. To run own simulation one must shock some exogenous variables in the model and then compare results with the original ones.  

         Simulations in this paper are based on five different scenarios of WTO agricultural negotiations results. In all scenarios it is assumed that only measures of market access (tariffs and tariff rate quotas) and export subsidies are going to liberalized. Possible changes in domestic support policy are deliberately neglected. These scenarios are based on following assumption:

·        scenario A – full multilateral elimination of export subsidies in equal rates in the years 2009-2013. It as a scenario of very “gentle” liberalization and quite possible, because during the Hong Kong Ministerial Conference member countries of WTO have already agreed for the elimination of export subsidies until 2013,

·        scenario B – full multilateral elimination of export subsides and full multilateral reduction of tariffs in equal rates in the years 2009-2013. It as a scenario of very “strict” liberalization and rather not possible,

·        scenarios C, D and E - full multilateral elimination of export subsides and tariff reduction based on modified proposals of US, EU and G-20 presented in the so called July Package (table 1).

 

Table 1. Tariff reduction scenarios based on proposals of US, EU and G-20 in July Package

Tariff base level

Tariff reduction  (in %)

Scenario C

(US proposal)

Scenario D

(EU proposal)

Scenario E

(G-20 proposal)

> 120%

60%-120%

20%-60%

0%-20%

85

75

65

55

60

50

45

35

75

65

55

45

 Source: Own elaboration based on WTO member countries proposals from WTO web page www.wto.org.

 

Scenarios B, C, D and E do not consider issue of sensible products, because countries did not present a list of such products. As far as tariff rate quotas are concerned, 50% increase of quota with lower tariff is assumed[5]. These scenarios also assume liberalization of agricultural trade in Russia because of a very possible accession of Russia to WTO. Generally, scenario A modifies 9 exogenous variables and scenarios B, C, D and E modify 114 exogenous variables. Results of AGLINK simulations based on this five scenarios are presented in table 2. Because of the size of the model and number of variables, only chosen countries and most important markets are going to be discussed.   

         On the majority of the markets, liberalization would lead to increase of prices over the base simulation, however the intensity of this process would be dependant on the single scenario assumption. Only prices for wheat, oil seeds and pork would behave differently and fall under the price level in base simulation. It is probably because protection measures on these markets are already relatively week and export of this goods from well-developed countries is not supported. However one needs to remember that price changes caused by export subsidies elimination and tariff reduction are not the only factors which can influence size of production and trade flows on given market. In many cases, agricultural markets are strongly dependant on domestic support policy, which is not analyzed in the scenarios. Nevertheless, on some markets reduction in trade policy measures would be enough to get some crucial adjustments of production and trade flows. Above statement concerns especially beef market. On beef world market, liberalization would lead to a small production increase and an essential increase in trade flows. The biggest growth (30%) in beef export in world scale would occur in scenario B, in which all export subsidies and tariff are eliminated. Scenario D, the one proposed by EU, would lead only to 17% growth in beef world export. In scenario A, in which only export subsidies are eliminated, export of beef on the world market would probably even fall below base simulation. This could be a result of a strong decline in beef export from EU. In this scenario, import of beef in EU would also decline because of emerge of excess supply, which could not be exported without subsidies. Reduction of very high tariffs for beef in EU (scenario B, C, D and E) would in turn lead to a very strong import increase (from 150% do even 270% dependant from scenario) and almost full reduction of beef export. Very expensive beef from EU could not manage competition on world market.

Table 2. Impact of different liberalization scenarios on chosen agricultural markets (results for the year 2014)

US

Wheat

Rice

Pork

Beef

SMP

Butter

Production (000 t)

Base simulation

61085,2

8209,7

9757,7

12786,1

545,6

657,9

Relative change to base simulation (%)

Scenario A

-0,2

0,0

-0,2

0,0

-1,4

-1,3

Scenario B

-0,4

0,1

-0,3

0,7

-1,3

-1,2

Scenario C

-0,3

0,1

-0,4

0,5

-1,3

-1,2

Scenario D

-0,3

0,1

-0,3

0,4

-1,4

-1,3

Scenario E

-0,3

0,1

-0,3

0,4

-1,3

-1,2

Export (000 t)

Base simulation

29244,7

4067,3

1341,4

1284,7

165,6

20,0

Relative change to base simulation (%)

Scenario A

-1,1

0,0

-1,1

-0,4

-4,2

-100,0

Scenario B

-2,8

0,3

-8,3

0,5

-6,1

-100,0

Scenario C

-2,5

0,3

-7,1

47,7

-5,9

-100,0

Scenario D

-2,2

0,2

-5,3

43,5

-5,4

-100,0

Scenario E

-2,4

0,3

-6,4

45,7

-5,7

-100,0

Import (000 t)

Base simulation

3116,6

522,2

970,9

1923,3

1,0

18,8

Relative change to base simulation (%)

Scenario A

0,0

0,0

-0,5

0,0

0,0

0,0

Scenario B

0,0

0,0

-1,4

23,6

0,0

0,0

Scenario C

0,0

0,0

-1,4

23,1

0,0

0,0

Scenario D

0,0

0,0

-1,1

23,0

0,0

0,0

Scenario E

0,0

0,0

-1,3

23,0

0,0

0,0

EU

Wheat

Rice

Pork

Beef

SMP

Butter

Production (000 t)

Base simulation

133220,9

1690,8

22370,1

7641,7

899,8

1897,2

Relative change to base simulation (%)

Scenario A

0,8

0,0

0,2

-0,3

-4,5

-1,7

Scenario B

2,2

0,0

-6,0

-10,8

-8,9

-2,8

Scenario C

1,9

0,0

-5,1

-9,2

-8,3

-2,6

Scenario D

1,6

0,0

-3,6

-6,6

-7,3

-2,4

Scenario E

1,8

0,0

-4,5

-8,1

-7,9

-2,5

Export (000 t)

Base simulation

15212,1

246,8

1445,3

200,6

105,3

184,6

Relative change to base simulation (%)

Scenario A

19,8

0,0

3,0

-59,8

-23,5

-41,6

Scenario B

57,3

0,0

18,2

-100,0

-8,1

-48,9

Scenario C

51,3

0,0

16,0

-100,0

-10,4

-48,2

Scenario D

41,7

0,0

12,4

-100,0

-14,3

-46,7

Scenario E

47,4

0,0

14,6

-100,0

-12,0

-47,7

Import (000 t)

Base simulation

6517,3

1268,5

32,0

723,0

9,3

79,0

Relative change to base simulation (%)

Scenario A

0,0

-0,1

0,0

-11,2

0,0

0,0

Scenario B

0,0

-0,3

0,0

269,4

0,0

0,0

Scenario C

0,0

-0,1

0,0

223,9

0,0

0,0

Scenario D

0,0

-0,2

0,0

151,7

0,0

0,0

Scenario E

0,0

-0,2

0,0

194,5

0,0

0,0

WORLD

Wheat

Rice

Pork

Beef

SMP

Butter

Production (000 t)

Base simulation

689776,9

484211,7

121327,8

76506,9

3405,4

9773,3

Relative change to base simulation (%)

Scenario A

-0,1

0,0

0,0

0,1

-1,0

-0,5

Scenario B

-0,5

-0,2

-1,1

1,3

-2,2

-1,9

Scenario C

-0,5

-0,2

-0,9

1,0

-2,1

-2,1

Scenario D

-0,4

-0,1

-0,7

0,6

-1,8

-1,5

Scenario E

-0,4

-0,1

-0,8

0,8

-2,0

-1,9

Export (000 t)

Base simulation

125463,3

33652,2

6811,6

10072,9

1050,7

794,3

Relative change to base simulation (%)

Scenario A

0,7

0,0

0,1

-0,8

-1,4

-6,3

Scenario B

3,2

1,0

5,8

30,0

-0,9

-6,4

Scenario C

2,8

0,9

5,0

24,1

-1,1

-6,4

Scenario D

2,2

0,8

4,3

17,6

-1,2

-6,4

Scenario E

2,5

0,8

4,7

21,3

-1,2

-6,4

Source: Own estimations based on AGLINK model.

Such a strong increase in beef import in EU would probably resulted from lower beef production and higher beef consumption caused by low beef prices. In many well-developed countries, cheaper beef would substitute pork consumption and production (US and EU). Liberalization would also lead to decline in export of dairy products from EU, which are presently supported with a very high export subsidies.   

         It is worth mentioning, that in different liberalization scenarios, export of wheat from EU would increase. This phenomenon can by explained by the wheat tariff reduction in developing countries[6] and higher wheat demand (for the feeds) on the world markets. Simulation results show that the wheat price would fall below the base simulation level. It would lead to decline in production in less developed countries. However, farmers in EU are supported with domestic policy measures (direct payments), which could sooth adverse effects of wheat price decline. In US one can expect essential changes on beef, dairy and pork markets. Adjustments on crop markets would be rather moderate, because crop producers in US are also protected by domestic support programs and trade measures have narrow meaning for them.    

 

Conclusions

         Agricultural policy of well-developed countries, because of their economic size, supports not only domestic farmers but also destabilizes world agricultural markets. Tariffs, export subsidies and domestic support measures lead to decline of agricultural prices on world markets under the level of profitability for many developing countries. Simultaneously, high financial support for farmers from well-developed countries allow them to compete and to win this competition both on domestic and world markets. Agricultural trade liberalization, to which tends WTO, could reduce price competitiveness of products from well-developed countries.

         Simulations with partial equilibrium model AGLINK show that elimination of export subsidies and reduction of tariffs would lead to stronger effects on meet markets than on crop markets. Special meaning for the developing countries would have liberalization on the beef and dairy market. Simulation results also indicate that on the majority of agricultural markets in well-developed countries effects of  export subsidies and tariff reduction would be rather weak. Farmers in these countries are after all supported with wide system of domestic policy measures. Additional, there exist a high probability, that eliminated subsidies and tariffs would be substituted with another form of support, which would compensate potential loses for farmers. One can conclude, that only liberalization of agricultural trade policy combined with liberalization of domestic support could lead to any essential shifts in the structure of international trade with agricultural products.           

           

Summary

         This paper considers some issues of the developed countries agricultural policy impact on the world agricultural markets. On the example of tariffs and export subsidies it was shown that these measures increase price competitiveness of the products from developed countries. Further, the partial equilibrium model AGLINK was used to evaluate potential consequences of agricultural trade liberalization under the WTO. It was proved that the biggest decline of competitiveness of agricultural products from developed countries would occur on the beef and dairy market.        

 

Bibliography:

Iwan B. (2006): Konkurencyjność polskich produktów mleczarskich na rynku Unii Europejskiej, [in:] Agrobiznes 2006. Konkurencja w agrobiznesie – jej uwarunkowania i następstwa, ed. S Urban, Wydawnictwo AE we Wrocławiu, Wrocław, p. 321-328.

Kasprzyk A. (2006): Konkurencyjność wybranych przedsiębiorstw przemysłu mięsnego w opinii konsumentów, [in:] Agrobiznes 2006. Konkurencja w agrobiznesie – jej uwarunkowania i następstwa, ed. S Urban, Wydawnictwo AE we Wrocławiu, Wrocław, p. 386-392.

Kosewska M., Kalicki A. (2008): Analiza stanu rokowań w ramach Światowej Organizacji Handlu (WTO) – tzw. Runda z Doha, FAPA FAMMU, Warszawa, p. 18.

Koo W., Kennedy P. (2006): The Impact of Agricultural Subsidies on Global Welfare, “American Journal of Agricultural Economics”, nr 88(5), p. 1219-1226.

Świerkocki J. (2004): Zarys międzynarodowych stosunków gospodarczych. PWE, Warszawa, p. 133.

Thompson W., Smith G., Elasri A. (2007): The Medium-Term Impacts of Trade Liberalization in OECD Countries on the Food Security of Nonmember Economies. [in:] Reforming Agricultural Trade for Developing Countries, ed. A. McCalla, J. Nash, The World Bank, Washington DC, p. 183.

van Tongeren F., van Meijl H., Surry I. (2001): Global models applied to agricultural and trade policies: a review and assessment, “Agricultural Economics”, nr 26, p. 150. 

Tyers R., Anderson K. (1992): Disarray in World Food Markets. A Quantitative Assessment. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, p. 21.

WTO Database, www.wto.org

 

 

 

 



[1] Argentina, Brazil, China and Russia.

[2] Model includes markets of basic temperate zone products: wheat, coarse grains (barley, corn, oats, rye, sorghum), rice, oil seeds (soya, rape, sunflower), meals (soya, rape, sunflower), oils (soya, rape, sunflower, palm), beef and veal, pork, poultry, sheep meat, eggs, milk, butter, chess, WMP, SMP, whey powder and casein.      

[3] Also 17 world prices.

[4] Because of the size of the model not all measures of domestic support on every market were included in model – only the one, which had a crucial impact on this markets. This allows to keep the model simple enough to be used by public.

[5] Modeling of tariff rate quotas constitutes a serious problem in all global models. Fill rate of this measure is at a very low level and it depends usually not from the economic variables, but from the administrative method of distribution and political issues. In this paper, tariff rate quotas with very low fill rate are neglected, a in the case of high fill rate it is assumed that import within quota with lower tariff is equal to  this quota.    

[6] Some of developing countries are wheat importers. In the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture they were either excluded from the tariff reduction or the reduction was weaker. However in analyzed scenarios multilateral reduction is assumed.